Related Subjects: Author Index
Book reviews for "Hodgson,_Geoffrey_M." sorted by average review score:

Economics and Utopia (Economics as Social Theory)
Published in Paperback by Routledge (1998)
Authors: Geoffrey M. Hodgson and Geoff Hodgson
Amazon base price: $35.95
Used price: $28.50
Buy one from zShops for: $35.50
Average review score:

Excellent and optimistic view of the future of economic life
Once again, Hodgson asks us to think BOLDLY and with confidence about our post cold-war economic future. The book does not romanticize in the least; rather it deepens the challenge he laid at the feet of academic orthodoxy and policy elites in western democracies in "Economics and Evolution". His view of the relation of scientific and technological knowledge and the possibilites they hold for transforming microeconomic transactions both within and between firms and his call for a dynamic reconfiguration of property rights so as to allocate resources in an ecologically sustainable and democratically humane manner, lay down a huge gauntlet for those who wish to maintain the status quo. Indeed he challenges us all to "to develop the capacity to unlearn, and learn anew" and see this process as the key to changing our core economic assumptions to embrace the evolutionary world we all inhabit. Capitalism is not the end of history, Hodgson says, and our persistent positing of socialism as it's "opposite" has outlived it's usefulnesss and blinds us to forms of economic organization which are more democratic, egalitarian and sustainable than either have ever been.


The Elgar Companion to Institutional and Evolutionary Economics
Published in Hardcover by Edward Elgar Pub (1994)
Authors: Geoffrey M. Hodgson, Warren J. Samuels, and Marc R. Tool
Amazon base price: $265.00
Average review score:

Important reference, various authors
The book comes in two volumes and consists essentially of solicited articles on various topics central to or important in institutional and evolutionary economics. The books therefore have entries on topics such as lock-in effects, Thorstein Veblen, old and new institutional economics, etc generally written by people who are active in research in that area.

The book is terrific for orienting oneself in these growth areas of economic research, and would be an important reference for university libraries. At the price, it would be prohibitive for most students but would be useful for academics specializing or developing an interest in this area.

The entries are followed by a bibliography to assist you in chasing up further levels of detail as required after reading an entry of interest.

Some entries (Eg Macroeconomics) have several entries from several authors, and it is quite interesting to see the different points of views taken.


Economics and Evolution: Bringing Life Back into Economics (Economics, Cognition, and Society)
Published in Hardcover by University of Michigan Press (1994)
Author: Geoffrey M. Hodgson
Amazon base price: $49.50
Used price: $60.00
Buy one from zShops for: $35.00
Average review score:

Nice, but with confusion over reductionism, and 'mechanism'
"People just do not maximize (utility) on a selfish basis every minute....the system would not work if they did...a consequence of that hypothesis would be the end of organized society."

K. Arrow

The author begins with the key question: why, in orthodox economic theory (neo-classical economics) is math superficially raised to such unwarranted heights while attempts to face empirical reality are so weak? Hodgson presents a stimulating (if too philosophic and also nonempiric) discussion of the ideas of Darwin, Smith, Spencer, Marx, Veblen, Marshall, Mayer, Schumpeter, and especially Hayek. A main question is: in a biologic analogy what, if any, are the economic anaogs of genes, the relatively invariant elements, the 'elementary particles' of a local economic system from which 'mutations' and 'selection' by the environment (the rest of the world economic system) can be understood.

Connected with the lack of obvious invariants in economic reality is the question how one can meaningfully divide the global system into 'isolated model equations plus environment.' If nothing can be isolated then it is impossible to discover any rule of mathematical law of time evolution. In particular, we cannot then treat the environment as an external field that 'selects' economically, unless we can empirically-accurately make the arbitrary division into 'system with initial conditions, plus environment'. This is in part a question of time scales.

Another problem is the author's confusion over the idea of 'evolution'. For evolution, meaning motion in time, to occur, organic behavior is not required. Every dynamical system has a time evolution operator that generates the trajectory. That mathematical analogs of mutations can be built into continuous time dynamical systems is likely because even certain Newtonian dynamical systems may be capable of universal computational capacity (maximum computational complexity, equivalent to a Turing machine). Therefore it is, at this stage, superficial to believe that the idea of organism is in conflict with the notion of mechanism. Every mathematical model is an example of 'mechanism' (1), albeit not necessarily Newtonian mechanism.

Third, (and correctly) implicit in the discussion is that complete reductionism (explanation of biology and economics in terms of quarks or atoms, e.g.) is mathematically impossible (in quantum theory, an Ohm meter has no definite reading, while DNA in nature behaves like a classical computer) and that some idea of hierarchy of description is necessary. But, how to identify empirically the necessary approximately invariant element in order to build a theory of this? Dawkins's idea of the reduction of behavior to genes is badly treated, but we really cannot rule out at this stage that some forms of mental behavior, at least, might be genetically determined, just as some known illnesses are genetically determined. Genetics 'looks like' physics precisely because genes are approximately invariant, like inertial masses. This analogy is not an accident. Mendel was trained in physics in Vienna, not in biology or philosophy.

Hayek's extreme free market ideas, usually not to be found in texts in the US, are given two chapters. One chapter is dedicated to his idea of the emergence of spontaneous order, which presumes (without any empirical evidence whatsoever) the existence of a stable, optimal outcome of an unregulated free market (he sketches the history of the emergence of the hierarchy of markets as a possible example). If such an outcome were guaranteed, as Hayek assumed, then we could do away with central banks (and forget Greenspan!), and denationalize money as The Austrian School of Economics advocates. The whole problem of the idea of preferences (utility functionals), however, is that they are neither time- nor path-independent.

In general, the orthodox school (and also Hayek) optimizes something or other (utility, or something else) whereas biological systems seem not to optimize anything, rather they are error-prone and error-correcting via gross redundancy (this was discussed mathematically by von Neumann). Maybe biological systems do not optimize anything. Likewise for economic systems.

The book is excessively philosophic, in the pre-scientific Aristotelian tradition. C. S. Pierce and John Dewey (who guaranteed that US public schools would be anti-academic, in part by making high schools a continuation of primary education instead of a transition to secondary education (see Hannah Arendt's Between 'Past and Future')). The author is dangerously unfriendly to Descartes, Galileo, and Newton (as if deterministic chaos were somehow a nonNewtonian phenomenon!) but based on a lack of understanding of how scientific knowledge is discovered. For a book on modern bioinformatics that makes the necessity of reductionism in biology quite clear, see W. R. Loewenstein's 'The Touchstone of Life: mplecular Information, Cell communication, and the foundations of Life'. This misfortune is connected with the usual failure to understand the difference between mathematical models and mathematical laws of nature that are based on observed local invariance principles, like the principle of relativity (the first physical principle discovered by Galileo). Popperian falsification is also given the short-schrift, praising Pierce against Descartes on the role of belief vs. skepticism!

Finally, metaphors are only used in the early stages of a theory when one understands little or nothing. Newtonian and Maxwellian laws, when generalized to admit 'learning' ala Hopfield's model of neural networks, are capable of universal computational capability. What can come out of these systems mathematically is therefore in principle unlimited. Whether they will be useful in understanding (macro-) biology and/or economics, or whether some simpler form of modelling will be more useful is still an open question.

I found the book to be both enlightening and irritating. The main important question raised the book: is anything out there approximately invariant, or is the use of mathematics and/or biologic ideas in economics relatively hopeless?

superb survey and novel presentation of economic ideas
Geoffrey Hodgson's work is a welcome relief from the economic drivel peddled by the interests of the powerful. More importantly, he shows the substantive links bewteen economics and our lives as biological agents in a multdimensional ecology we barely understand. In the process he examines the strengths and weaknesses of many of the great economic thinkers of the past. It is a call to arms for all those who see consequences of bad economic thinking all around them in devastated communities and diminished ecosystems. This is a must read for all those dissatisfied with our current economic world view and want to debate economists on their own terms.


After Marx and Sraffa: Essays in Political Economy
Published in Hardcover by Palgrave Macmillan (1991)
Author: Geoffrey M. Hodgson
Amazon base price: $69.95
Average review score:
No reviews found.

Economics and Biology
Published in Hardcover by Edward Elgar Pub (1995)
Author: Geoffrey M. Hodgson
Amazon base price: $290.00
Average review score:
No reviews found.

Economics and Institutions: A Manifesto for a Modern Institutional Economics
Published in Hardcover by University of Pennsylvania Press (1988)
Author: Geoffrey M. Hodgson
Amazon base price: $48.95
Used price: $60.00
Average review score:
No reviews found.

The Economics of Institutions (Elgar Reference Collection)
Published in Hardcover by Edward Elgar Pub (1994)
Author: Geoffrey M. Hodgson
Amazon base price: $245.00
Average review score:
No reviews found.

The Foundations of Evolutionary Economics, 1890-1973 (Elgar Reference Collection)
Published in Hardcover by Edward Elgar Pub (1998)
Author: Geoffrey M. Hodgson
Amazon base price: $335.00
Average review score:
No reviews found.

A Modern Reader in Institutional and Evolutionary Economics: Key Concepts (In Association With the European Association of Evolutionary Political econOmy (Eaepe).)
Published in Paperback by Edward Elgar Pub (31 July, 2002)
Authors: Geoffrey M. Hodgson and European Association for Evolutionary Political Economy
Amazon base price: $25.00
Average review score:
No reviews found.

Related Subjects: Author Index

Reviews are from readers at Amazon.com. To add a review, follow the Amazon buy link above.