Used price: $5.30
Collectible price: $12.94
Finley then goes literary, eschewing anthropology and archaeology and instead analyzing the texts of the Iliad and the Odyssey. From the stories of Homer, he reconstructs the sort of society in the Homeric heroes lived, in terms of its economy, its social structure, and its morals and values.
The picture he draws is interesting and compelling, above all because it is consistent. Its consistency is, of course, an argument in favor of the view that the Homeric world really did exist (i.e., that gods and magic and specific names aside, the cultural world described by Homer is authentic, and not an artistic creation). Moreover, because the culture is consistent, an understanding of it helps a reader to interpret sometimes puzzling actions on the part of Homer's heroes. This is therefore important secondary reading to accompany any reading of Homer.
List price: $49.95 (that's 30% off!)
Used price: $10.49
Collectible price: $3.89
This is a very dishonest way to carry out business, and Finley is fairly even-handed in his condemnations. However, Finley does avoid answering the larger question, why does the practice continue?
I think anyone seeking to understand the real workings of history by one committed to a truthful exploration of the past, rather than someone's hidden agenda (and the best seller lists are frequently filled with these) should sit down and read this fascinating book.
List price: $14.00 (that's 20% off!)
Used price: $1.25
Collectible price: $9.95
Buy one from zShops for: $2.99
Used price: $0.94
Buy one from zShops for: $8.58
Finley originally published this book in 1970. He republished it in 1981 to incorporate new archeological discoveries. He has examined the ancient Greek world chronologically from Early Minoan to the Persian Wars from the social, economic, and political aspects.
Archeological evidence is valuable for describing and dividing changes in antiquity. Divisions were created as advancements occurred. One example of an advancement cited by Finley is the burial ritual. Much can be learned about a society by studying the way they bury their dead. The Cyclades included marble idols in the graves. The Cretans did nothing majestic with their tombs. The gold disks the Mycenaeans buried in their shaft-graves and the later pottery found in Mycenaean Tholos-tombs help to date the burial sites. By studying advancements in burial designs of these different groups, one can decipher the stages of development for a group of people. After determining who was buried in the tombs, one can interpret who and what traits were more honored by the more decorative ornamentation found.
When read along with a more in-depth and inclusive textbook designed to instruct the unfamiliar student with ancient times, this book is most helpful. It includes many terms assumed to be familiar but which are not, and therefore, definitions of these terms are needed. By reading a supplementary list of terms and committing to memory many of the characters names, approaching the text became easier.
The book includes discussions of various differences and similarities between modern and ancient science. Ancient thinkers seemed less concerned with the practical potential of their ideas. The pursuit of knowledge for knowledge sake, with a few notable exceptions, was a worthy enough endeavour in itself. They saw the natural world as something more to be studied than "tamed". "Science" was a more vaguely defined discipline; few people practised it much less got paid for it. The book discusses the various streams and ideas which grew about, with, and around it, such as medicine, philosophy, astronomy, mathematics, and biology. The Pythagorians, Platonists, Milesians, Aristotle, Thales, and Anaximander are all names which come to the fore, but unfortunately, their contribution withers away far too quickly in the history of the world. Some interesting points I noted were early suggestions that man had sprung from other organisms, (namely fish), the problem of change, theories concerning the nature of matter-you know-elements, atoms and so on.
A look into the thinking of the early Greeks is in part a mirror into the heart and nature of our society. My only complaint with the book is that we have so little remaining information about these thinkers and their times.
Please, archaeologists and the like, find much more about the Greeks in some colossal discovery of thousands of well-preserved, buried manuscripts in a buried ancient city somewhere about Greece, so we can know more about the ancient world.
Used price: $6.95
Collectible price: $7.93
However, Finlay's as author is not as satisfying.
The foreword to Finlay's book is good. It puts Finlay's contribution into a larger context and, in particular, pointing out Max Weber's influence on Finlay.
Max Weber noticed that most people are mainly interested in social prestige, not the means thereto, and, more specifically, that the modern means to prestige is not the traditional (ie., ancient) means thereto.
As a result of the foreward, I immediately ordered Weber's ostensible masterwork "Die Protestantische Ethik und der 'Geist des Kapitalismus'" (written 1904 with revision 1920).
Finlay himself does not explicity appear to recognise his debt to Weber. He refers to Weber's contemporaries (Rostovtzeff & co.).
As the author points out, very little was probably ever written in ancient times - and much less has been delivered down to us through the passage of time - regarding "economic" matters, the writing and reading public being consituted essentially by well-born persons with private incomes, who were generally interested in the (for them) more appropriate topics of poetry, rhetoric, religion, philosophy and heroic military exploits.
Hence research on this subject is difficult.
Also, the book is rather tedious and the amount of repitition and ampflication on essentially obvious points gets a bit monotonous.
Having said that, the whole subject matter was interesting, and the pointers to other authors useful.
The economic model which is developed is typical social sciences stuff: simplest ideas expressed cryptically as pseudo-mathematical charts. One can overlook this.
At the end of the day, the most worthwhile knowledge which I gained from Finlay's work was the knowledge that there was a Roman writer called Vitruvius who wrote a work on Architecture at around the time of Christ which remained the standard work on that subject for at least 1,500 years.
In the meantime I have read Vitruvius and found him to be both useful and entertaining.
Now I'll read Max Weber.
Finley first examines status and statistics. What constituted status in the ancient world? For one thing, class and status were independent. A person could be of low class, but very high status. Pallas and Narcissus, the freedmen that served the emperor Claudius, come to mind here. Both were extremely high placed in society. They were rich beyond the dreams of avarice, but their class was lower than that of a senator. Finley's examination of statistics in ancient Rome is telling. In our world, it is inconceivable that the economy could be discussed without using stats. In Rome, this was not the case. Certainly, there were receipts of expenditures and interest rates on loans, but numbers just didn't hold the allure in Rome that they do today. The absence of guilds and interdependent markets, according to Finley, certainly has something to do with this. Most merchandise was locally made and consumed locally, or shipped directly to Rome. There was no need for corporations or massive transportation of goods (except grain shipments to Rome) between regions.
Finley's discussions on slavery are certainly enlightening. Finley believes slavery was necessary to the Roman world because it reinforced status. The highest strata of society disdained work, so having a dependent class of workers was essential to watch over estates and manage businesses. One of the surprising insights Finley provides is in exploding the myth that slavery is inefficient. Finley shows that the large landowners had money to burn due to the labor of slaves, as did the plantation owners in the American South. I'm not so sure I agree with this argument. To the extent that slaves were profitable in Rome, it would seem that this had much to do with the Roman system of slavery. The Romans had a process called "Peculium" in which slaves were given seed money by their masters to start businesses. Slaves could keep some of the profits from this system and eventually buy their freedom, as well as learn a trade. This is an excellent incentive to work hard, thereby increasing profits to their owners. I don't think slaves in the Americas had the same incentives.
Although the book is much more complex than the poor description I've given above, this review should provide ample initiative to read Finley. Even a beginner to Roman history could get much out of this book. Finley, despite some early hiccups, has a smooth writing style that is sympathetic to the newbie. Many a professional scholar has received inspiration from Finley. Highly Recommended.
List price: $16.95 (that's 30% off!)
Used price: $0.85
Collectible price: $3.00
Buy one from zShops for: $4.99
Used price: $6.50
Used price: $10.39
Buy one from zShops for: $9.82
This is a superb reference guide to assist one's journey thru the archaic but wonderous historical niche of the ancient Greeks. For those who have already read the works of Homer, the present work is a very useful tool to examine more closely the subtle information provided in even the most remote passages of the epics.
This book is highly recommended to anyone who has ever read Homer, as well as anyone who would ever like to. For students of Greek history and literature, this one is a can't miss!